Graft Paper: Harvard's Ben Olken, 32, Studies the Economics of Bribery and Assassination in Developing Nations. Plus, "Bowling Alone" in Indonesia

By Moynihan, Michael | The American (Washington, DC), January-February 2008 | Go to article overview

Graft Paper: Harvard's Ben Olken, 32, Studies the Economics of Bribery and Assassination in Developing Nations. Plus, "Bowling Alone" in Indonesia


Moynihan, Michael, The American (Washington, DC)


[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]

In his nondescript office on Massachusetts Avenue in Cambridge, nestled in a far-off corner of Harvard Square, Ben Olken ruminates on the economic consequences of tyrannicide, the damaging effects of television on social cohesion, and the byzantine system of bribery in Indonesia. Olken, a 32-year-old with an undergraduate degree from Yale (in mathematics and "ethics, politics, and economics") and an economies doctorate from Harvard, is a rising star in the field of developmental economics. Olken is currently a member of Harvard's Society of Fellows, a prestigious institution within the institution, where the best young scholars pursue what interests them. Among economists alone, former Junior Fellows include Paul Samuelson, Carl Kaysen, Jeffrey Sachs, Steven Levitt, and James Tobin.

Olken is "one of the most exciting young scholars in economics," his Harvard adviser, Lawrence F. Katz, former chief economist to the U.S. Labor Department, told The Chronicle of Higher Education. He is.

Olken wonders whether economic development and the path to democratization are shaped more by broad historical forces or by the actions of specific leaders--be they democratically elected prime ministers or thuggish authoritarians. With the assistance of his frequent research partner Ben Jones, an economist at Northwestern, Olken has challenged broadly held assumptions by publishing a pair of papers asking how heads of state affect economic outcomes and democracy.

In "Hit or Miss? The Effect of Assassinations on Institutions and War," Olken and Jones looked at the effects of political assassination, using a strict empirical methodology that takes into account economic conditions at the time of the killing and what Olken calls a "novel data set" of assassination attempts, successful and unsuccessful, between 1875 and 2004.

Olken and Jones discovered that a country was "more likely to see democratization following the assassination of an autocratic leader," but found no substantial "effect following assassinations--or assassination attempts--on democratic leaders." They concluded that "on average, successful assassinations of autocrats produce sustained moves toward democracy." The researchers also found that assassinations have no effect on the inauguration of wars, a result that "suggests that World War I might have begun regardless of whether or not the attempt on the life of Archduke Franz Ferdinand in 1914 had succeeded or failed."

In "Do Leaders Matter? National Leadership and Growth since World War II," Olken and Jones explored whether "individual political leaders make a difference in economic growth." This is tricky business for the researcher because, as Olken explains, a country's economic situation can affect the election of a leader: when the economic outlook is good, for instance, presidents are more likely to be reelected. So Olken and Jones looked at 57 leaders who died in office from accidents or natural causes and "found big changes in growth when autocratic leaders die in office--both positive and negative," but no substantial change when democratic leaders died in office. "The results suggest," they write, "that individual leaders can play crucial roles in shaping the growth of nations," provided they are ruling with minimal or nonexistent checks and balances to their power (think Augusto Pinochet or Robert Mugabe).

A significant portion of Olken's field research is conducted in Indonesia, a country for which he has much affection: he has previously lived there, speaks the language, and understands the country's social mores.

So when he decided to test the validity of the much-debated "bowling alone" theory--Harvard political scientist Robert Putnam's argument that television, among other "individualizing" cultural phenomena, has had a negative effect on the social fabric of the West--he found himself in Indonesia, a country not affected by many of the cultural externalities that compromise Putnam's American-based study. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA 8, MLA 7, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Note: primary sources have slightly different requirements for citation. Please see these guidelines for more information.

Cited article

Graft Paper: Harvard's Ben Olken, 32, Studies the Economics of Bribery and Assassination in Developing Nations. Plus, "Bowling Alone" in Indonesia
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen
Items saved from this article
  • Highlights & Notes
  • Citations
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA 8, MLA 7, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Search by... Author
    Show... All Results Primary Sources Peer-reviewed

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.