Macroeconomic Policy in a Transitional Environment: Romania, 1989-1994

By Poirot, Clifford | Journal of Economic Issues, December 1996 | Go to article overview

Macroeconomic Policy in a Transitional Environment: Romania, 1989-1994


Poirot, Clifford, Journal of Economic Issues


When I finished reading the novel 1984, by George Orwell, I asked myself if there existed anything worse, more deprived, more inhuman than a fixed life set definitively in misery and terror? I believe that even then I had the answer in mind, though I formulated it explicitly later when I began to write this book. Yes, it exists: A change which changes nothing.

- George Paun, author of 1994: Schirabarea Care Nu Schimba Nimic (A Change Which Changes Nothing).

There has been increasing interest in comparing the difficulties of implementing macroeconomic stabilization programs in Latin America to those of Central and Eastern Europe [Ramirez 1993; Edwards 1992]. As in Latin America, stabilization efforts in Eastern and Central Europe face daunting obstacles: hyperinflation punctuated by chronic trade deficits, sharp currency devaluations, the depletion of hard currency reserves, and steep drops in GDP. The combination of "depressionary hyperinflation" and severe external disequilibrium casts an immediate pallor on efforts at macroeconomic stabilization in Central and Eastern Europe. Yet there is growing evidence that the problem may in fact be more fundamental in nature than most macroeconomists have considered.

A growing number of economists now realize that the overall institutional environment greatly restricts the options available to policymakers in both Latin American and former socialist countries. Of particular relevance to policymakers are the performance and structure of the banking system, the behavior and level of development of capital markets, the existence or nonexistence of a self-regulating market system in the goods market, the extent to which an economy is integrated into international markets, and the ability of financial institutions to channel capital to productive investments [Schlack 1993; Edwards 1992; Stiglitz 1992].

If there are no institutional mechanisms for channeling capital into productive enterprises, then lowering or raising interest rates is unlikely to affect either real or nominal output or the inflation rate. Similarly, if central bank control of the commercial banking system is absent and if consumers have no confidence in the commercial banking system, then efforts to target growth in the money stock, however it is measured, are predestined to fail. Removal of price controls does not automatically lead to increased supplies of goods if the industrial sector is incapable of, or unwilling to, increase production in response to price increases. If recovery of industrial production faces structural obstacles to recovery, then restrictive aggregate demand policies are likely to be undermined by enterprise demands for credit and state subsidies. Furthermore, when confronted with the prospect of widespread bankruptcy in the industrial sector, governments seldom, if ever, heed the call for discipline. Indeed, according to some economists, the failure to adhere to rigid monetary discipline in the face of severe structural imbalances may in fact be a good thing [Ramirez 1993].

A further point that has not received appreciable attention from economists is the extent to which the political environment can promote or inhibit meaningful economic reforms. When polities lack a democratic political culture, even the formal observance of democratic rules can obscure rampant corruption and the influence of extremists and chauvinist political groupings. Pervasive corruption and lack of trust by the public in the fairness of the rules surrounding privatization efforts undermine public confidence in reform efforts. In both Latin America and in former socialist countries, the legacy of authoritarian rule casts a pallor over the political landscape.

These problems are probably more severe in the former socialist countries of Central and Eastern Europe than in Latin America. Decades of development efforts, integration into world economic structures, and a history of experience in dealing with western commercial banks and international lending institutions have given Latin American countries a degree of institutional experience in policy implementation. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Macroeconomic Policy in a Transitional Environment: Romania, 1989-1994
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.