Taxes, Torts, and the Toxics Release Inventory: Congressional Voting on Instruments to Control Pollution

By Hamilton, James T. | Economic Inquiry, October 1997 | Go to article overview

Taxes, Torts, and the Toxics Release Inventory: Congressional Voting on Instruments to Control Pollution


Hamilton, James T., Economic Inquiry


I. INTRODUCTION

Governments can choose from a wide variety of policy instruments to control pollution, including tax and subsidy schemes, marketable permits, information provision programs, liability systems with well-defined property rights, and command and control selection of emission standards or technologies. Economists throughout the 1980s devoted significant effort to modeling the relative merits of these instruments. The question of why politicians would prefer one manner of controlling pollution over another also attracted attention, starting with Buchanan and Tullock's [1975] positive theory of externality control in which polluters find direct regulatory controls on emissions more profitable than pollution taxes. Theories of instrument selection have been developed in which politicians choose policies based on the relative costs and benefits to shareholders, workers, and environmentalists, are affected by the constraints imposed by political institutions, and are driven to select the most efficient policy instrument to achieve a given level of redistribution.(1) To date, however, there have been few empirical tests of what drives instrument selection in environmental policy.

There is a large empirical literature devoted to explaining the level of support for environmental programs in Congress. Most articles focus on the degree to which a legislator's stand on a given environmental bill can be explained by narrow district interests (generally the material interests of constituents) or by ideology (either constituents' or the member's own policy preferences). Studies of voting on environmental legislation by Ackerman and Hassler [1981], Crandall [1983], Pashigian [1985], and Yandle [1989] offer evidence that legislators' actions are in part explained by the district- or state-level impacts of proposed legislation on their constituents. Kalt and Zupan [1984] find that after controlling for constituents' material self-interest in proposed strip mining legislation, the ideology of constituents and the personal ideologies of their representatives influence voting on this aspect of environmental preservation. As Grier [1993] demonstrates, debate over the general role of the legislator's specific ideology in voting continues. In studying votes in the House and Senate on the proposed size of the Superfund during debate over the program's renewal, Hird [1993] concludes that "congressional voting on Superfund is found to represent legislator's environmental and liberal ideologies as much as (if not more than) narrowly-defined self-interest." He links the importance of ideology to voting on Superfund in part to the bill's symbolic environmental appeal.

In environmental legislation, the final impact of a bill on industry and the environment often depends on issues resolved through technical amendments. Downs's theory of rational ignorance and Arnold's theory of the degree to which constituents will link Congressional actions with real world outcomes predict that members of Congress may be less constrained by general constituent interests on amendment votes since these votes are less likely to be covered in the media than are final legislative votes. As Denzau and Munger [1986] and Grier and Munger [ 1991] note, groups with specific interests such as affected industries may find it less costly to persuade a member of Congress to vote their way on a measure if the representative's constituents are supportive of or indifferent to the measure. In the case of technical amendments, affected parties may be more influential than on highly visible votes because the lack of media coverage translates into a lower probability that the vote will become a major campaign issue in future elections. This implies that voting on the instruments to control pollution will be driven in part by the specific district-level costs and benefits of these measures, while voting on the final passage of a bill will be more driven by general constituent interests. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Taxes, Torts, and the Toxics Release Inventory: Congressional Voting on Instruments to Control Pollution
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.