Minimum Wage Increases and the Business Failure Rate

By Waltman, Jerold; McBride, Allan et al. | Journal of Economic Issues, March 1998 | Go to article overview

Minimum Wage Increases and the Business Failure Rate


Waltman, Jerold, McBride, Allan, Camhout, Nicole, Journal of Economic Issues


One of the staple arguments that business groups, especially those representing small businesses, use against minimum wage increases is that they will drive a number of firms out of business entirely. The logic is simple and straightforward. Since business firms are presumably employing resources at maximum efficiency, rising labor costs must be absorbed somewhere. One alternative is price increases; but some industries will encounter an inelastic demand for their products, and consumers will spend elsewhere. Falling revenues for that industry will result in some firms being pushed into bankruptcy. Alternatively, companies may reduce the number of workers, but then fewer customers can be served, and again the less efficient firms go under. Finally, firms may substitute technology for workers; this requires capital investment, which some firms cannot afford. The less heavily capitalized will consequently exit the market. Have higher minimum wage rates, though, been associated with actual increases in the rate of business failures?

Dunn and Bradstreet [1985] has published data on rates of business failures from 1926 to 1983.(1) To shed some empirical light on the alleged relationship between minimum wages and business failures, we conducted three exercises utilizing the failure rates from 1949 (the year of adoption of the first postwar increase in the minimum wage) to 1983. First, we asked whether the failure rate during the years when the minimum wage rose was higher than the longer-term average. Second, we asked the same question for each of the years following immediately after a minimum wage hike went into effect (referred to hereafter as the "lag years"). Third, we examined the effect of the magnitude of the increase in the minimum wage on the failure rate.

Figure 1 presents the actual rate of business failures, with the years of minimum wage increases noted, while Figure 2 does the same for the lag years. The overall mean failure rate is 47.5 per 10,000 concerns.

Comparing the years when there was an increase in the minimum wage with other years, the rate was 43.2 in the former and 50.0 in the latter. Shifting to the lag years, the situation is only marginally different. The means are 48.4 for the year following a hike in the minimum wage and 47.6 in the remaining years.

Table 1. Business Failure Rates in Selected Years

                                             Mean Number of Failures
                                             (Per 10,000 Concerns)

Years with minimum wage increases                    43.2

Years with no increase in the minimum wage           50.0

Years immediately after those in which
minimum wage increases took effect                   48.4

Years other than the years immediately
after those in which minimum wage
increases took effect                                47.6

Perhaps even more interesting is the result of regressing the magnitude of the minimum wage increase on the failure rates for both the year of the increase and the lag year. If the position of business spokespersons is correct, then larger increases in the minimum wage should lead to more failures than smaller ones do. However, what happens is just the opposite.

The regression coefficients are b = -69. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Minimum Wage Increases and the Business Failure Rate
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.