Adam Smith's Higher Vision of Capitalism

By Alvey, James E. | Journal of Economic Issues, June 1998 | Go to article overview

Adam Smith's Higher Vision of Capitalism


Alvey, James E., Journal of Economic Issues


Adam Smith had a vision of capitalism that was much more elevated than that of most neoclassical economists. His ideal society would satisfy the ends of human nature as he identified them, and it is from this standard that Smith criticized defective societies, praised good ones, and propounded a detailed agenda of reform. His views on human flourishing were also much richer than is often thought to be the case.

Smith said that there are five explicit ends of nature (self-preservation, procreation of the species, order, happiness, and perfection of the species) [Smith 1976a, 77, 166, 168](1) and an implicit goal of freedom. According to Smith, the satisfaction of the ends of nature could only occur in a particular type of prosperous, modern, free-trade commercial society. But I will argue that Smith's six ends together constitute a "thick"(2) notion of the human good, one that is not bourgeois.

What role does government play in the achievement of the ends of nature? In the Wealth of Nations (WN), Smith said that "according to the system of natural liberty, the sovereign has only three duties to attend to," namely, external security, internal security (law and law enforcement), and "certain public works and certain public institutions" [Smith 1976b, 687-8]. Apart from these three duties, there is also a little-noticed fourth duty:

The laws of all civilized nations . . . impose upon men many . . . duties of beneficence. The civil magistrate is entrusted with the power . . . of promoting the prosperity of the commonwealth, by establishing good discipline, and by discouraging every sort of vice and impropriety; he may prescribe rules, therefore, which not only prohibit mutual injuries among fellow-citizens, but command mutual good offices to a certain degree [Smith 1976a, 81; emphasis added].

This very broad duty, discussed in Smith's Theory of Moral Sentiments (TMS), is called the TMS duty hereafter.

No mention is made of this latter duty by the many neoclassical economists who see Smith as an intellectual forebear. Perhaps because Smith referred to "the system of natural liberty," neoclassical economists have often interpreted Smith to have been a proponent of negative liberty or an advocate of an "area within which man can act unobstructed by others" [Berlin 1969, quoted in Justman 1993, 24]. Clearly, the TMS duty would not be required under a system aimed at maximizing negative liberty. Smith's ideal is much richer than this.

Preservation, Procreation, Order, and Freedom

Let us turn to fleshing out the nature of Smith's ideal. Obviously everyone must be provided with the means for bare preservation. Smith argued that bare preservation is not sufficient: comfortable preservation should be provided not only to allow for the procreation and nurturing of a considerable family, but for the comforts of life and happiness. The goal is comfortable preservation, as is evident in the/MS duty that the government must strive to promote "the prosperity of the commonwealth" [Smith 1976a, 81]. This goal of comfortable preservation is also one means to happiness [Smith 1976a, 297; 1976b, 99].

While government has little role to play directly in the provision of subsistence [Smith 1976b, 524-43 passim], according to Smith, it has a great role to play in the provision of the end of order. Of the three WN duties of government, the first two are related to order. The first, and presumably most important, duty of government is external security [Smith 1976b, 687]. The survival of society requires military defence. Smith argued that in commercial society, protected by a standing army, the concern for "national power" is solved by maximizing economic growth [see Hollander 1973, 310]. In the modern era, generally, defense, individual welfare, national wealth, and the country's power go together [Smith 1976b, 48, 372].

In addition, government has another role to play in the provision of order. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Adam Smith's Higher Vision of Capitalism
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.