Evolutionary Alternatives to Equilibrium Economics: Some Suggested Applications

By Pluta, Joseph E. | The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, October 2010 | Go to article overview

Evolutionary Alternatives to Equilibrium Economics: Some Suggested Applications


Pluta, Joseph E., The American Journal of Economics and Sociology


Introduction

The absence of an empirically verified "balancing of forces" or "state of rest" in economic phenomena remains an embarrassment to the mainstream of a discipline that seeks quantitative precision and confirmation of theories using hard data. Equilibrium models that casually accept Jeremy Bentham's hedonistic utilitarianism and assume consumer rationality as well as maximization of utility subject to a budget constraint still grace the literature in leading professional journals. Despite voluminous research output that documents alternative firm motivation and strategy, businesses large and small still supposedly achieve equilibrium when they either maximize profit, revenue, or market share (or perhaps minimize cost). Despite the arguments of John Maynard Keynes to the contrary, macroeconomic models still seek the ideal equilibrium with a high rate of economic growth accompanied by little or no inflation and full employment. Despite the existence of multiple prices in numerous markets, students are still taught that a single price results from independently determined supply and demand equations.

In place of the static notion of equilibrium, the more dynamic circular and cumulative causation (CCC) framework has long held substantial promise of greater explanatory power while (and likely, because of) incorporating a far wider array of both economic and noneconomic variables. This article briefly surveys the origin of both concepts, illustrates in general terms the CCC method of analysis, documents recent research advances, and suggests some possible future applications.

Background

Originally advanced in the physical sciences, equilibrium was uncritically adapted for use in a fledgling economics profession seeking scientific stature. The great scientist Isaac Newton (1687) depicted the universe as a mechanism that was understandable and potentially reducible to mathematical laws. (1) His law of gravity stated that heavenly bodies remain in motion because of a balancing of forces that prevent them from colliding, a rather impressive "equilibrium" in physics and astronomy. As a result, much like the spring of a clock (Canterbery 1987: 29), the universe functions smoothly and continuously in endless harmony. Its complex precision, the argument continues, was the work of a skillful, artistic Creator who, upon completing his project, left it alone to run itself. The perfection of this mechanism was due to laws of nature that, Newton believed, applied not only to the cosmos but also to the smallest of entities within it.

Attracted to the novelty and logic of Newton's arguments, many intellectuals sought to apply them to areas outside of physics. As the 18th century began, leading European thinkers became increasingly enamored of Newton's mechanistic view and of the prospect of scientific measurement. The task of humanity, some reasoned, was to assure that all activity was consistent with this natural law. Virtually no one questioned the legitimacy of applying principles that govern inanimate objects to living human beings. So impressive were Newton's analyses that extending them wherever possible simply seemed like the correct thing to do. Natural law led to the concept of a natural economic order. If a Supreme Being created a magnificent universe with all its components functioning so efficiently that further intervention was unnecessary, what possible justification could there be for interfering with the natural operation of the economy? With this leap of faith and dubious logic, minimal government intervention achieved a supposed scientific status that meshed nicely with existing cultural norms, further contributing to its acceptance and popularity.

With the passage of time, a relatively large group of economists has come to accept some scientific and economic concepts more than others but has consistently built upon Newton's equilibrium model. His development of the calculus enabled easy identification of maximum and minimum values. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Evolutionary Alternatives to Equilibrium Economics: Some Suggested Applications
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.