The Role of Model Specification in Finding the Influence of Ownership and Regulatory Regime on Utility Cost: The Case of Swedish Electricity Distribution

By Soderberg, Magnus | Contemporary Economic Policy, April 2011 | Go to article overview

The Role of Model Specification in Finding the Influence of Ownership and Regulatory Regime on Utility Cost: The Case of Swedish Electricity Distribution


Soderberg, Magnus, Contemporary Economic Policy


I. INTRODUCTION

The restructuring of network industries during the last two decades has typically involved privatization of state- and municipally owned utilities and a change in regulatory regime from cost-of-service, or rate-of-return, regulation to incentive-based regulation. These re-regulatory initiatives have been encouraged by economic theories that predict that private suppliers and competition increase cost efficiency. (1) Such outcomes have in fact been observed in electricity and water distribution (Kumbhakar and Hjalmarsson 1998; Saal and Parker 2000). (2)

Nevertheless, the restructuring seen in different countries varies from complete privatization of multiple utility services and a heavy reliance on cost incentives, in for example England and Wales, to no or only marginal adjustments, exemplified by the water, wastewater, and district heating sectors in Sweden. (3)

The wide variety of adopted policies can be attributed to the empirical difficulty of establishing a unified view of how utility performance is affected by different ownership and regulatory arrangements. The mainstream predictions are questioned by, for example, Kwoka (2005a, 2005b) and Bhattacharyya et al. (1995), who suggest that publicly owned utilities are more cost efficient in electricity and water distribution, respectively, whereas others argue that ownership is only relevant in combination with other market and utility characteristics, such as type of regulation (Aroncena and Waddams Price 2002; Berg, Lin, and Tsaplin 2005) and utility size (Bhattacharyya et al. 1995). In terms of regulation, incentive models have been found to improve welfare (Estache and Rossi 2005) but Goto and Tsutsui (2008) find no effect of deregulatory initiatives in the U.S. electricity distribution, although the precise natures of the pre- and post-regulatory regimes are unclear in their case. (4) Aubert and Reynaud (2005) find that water utilities are more cost efficient under rate-of-return regulation than under price cap regulation. The authors attribute this outcome to the extensive access to information that supplements the particular rate-of-return regime they investigate.

A tentative explanation to why conclusions vary is the specific conditions that prevail in each country and industry; however, the studies referred to above also suggest that ownership and regulation might not affect performance by themselves but rather through combinations with other factors. In addition, behavioral assumptions and model specifications vary, which can potentially inflate differences in empirical outcomes. Bhattacharyya et al. (1995), Berg, Lin, and Tsaplin (2005), Hattori, Jamasb, and Pollitt (2005), Aubert and Reynaud (2005), Pombo and Taborda (2006), and Goto and Tsutsui (2008) all use stochastic frontier (i.e., dual disturbance) specifications, whereas Kwoka (2005a, 2005b) and Saal and Parker (2000) use single disturbance specifications. The choice between dual and single disturbance specifications is related to the assumption of utility objective, because a frontier specification rests on an assumption of cost-minimization while a function through the average of the data assumes that utilities follow any arbitrary objective. If it can be assumed that utilities minimize costs, then frontier methods have superior economic properties because the presence of a frontier is consistent with the behavior of economic optimization with a departure from the frontier interpreted as a lack of ability and/or luck. However, the choice of utility objective is not straightforward and although a majority of the studies surveyed above apply frontier specifications, it has been claimed that a cost-minimizing assumption could be overly restrictive (Kwoka 2005a). It can nevertheless be argued that most incentive-based approaches encourage cost-minimization and they typically compose a double incentive structure to separately reward frontier reductions and penalize inefficiency. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

The Role of Model Specification in Finding the Influence of Ownership and Regulatory Regime on Utility Cost: The Case of Swedish Electricity Distribution
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.