The Unemployment Volatility Puzzle: The Role of Matching Costs Revisited

By Silva, Jose I.; Toledo, Manuel | Economic Inquiry, January 2013 | Go to article overview

The Unemployment Volatility Puzzle: The Role of Matching Costs Revisited


Silva, Jose I., Toledo, Manuel, Economic Inquiry


I. INTRODUCTION

The Mortensen-Pissarides (MP) search and matching model (Mortensen and Pissarides 1994; Pissarides 1985, 2000) studies the dynamics of unemployment in an environment where jobs are continuously created and destroyed. A sequence of papers by Costain and Reiter (2008), Hall (2005), and Shimer (2005) have questioned the model's ability to match the observed cyclical fluctuations of the unemployment rate in the United States. For example, Shimer shows that under a reasonable calibration strategy, the MP model predicts that the vacancy-unemployment ratio and the average labor productivity should have nearly the same volatility. In contrast, the standard deviation of the vacancy-unemployment ratio in the United States is almost 20 times as large as the standard deviation of the average labor productivity. This large discrepancy between the volatility implied by the model and the data constitutes an empirical puzzle, known as the unemployment volatility puzzle.

Pissarides (2009) shows that introducing fixed matching costs into the model (e.g., training costs) can significantly increase the volatility of labor-market outcomes, such as tightness and the job finding rate. He points out that this result is obtained without inducing a counterfactually low volatility in the wages of new jobs. In his quantitative exercise, Pissarides only considers sunk fixed matching costs and argues that non-sunk fixed training costs play a similar role. More in detail, Pissarides (2009, 1364) writes the following with respect to matching costs: "they are sunk once the wage bargain is concluded and the worker takes up the position, but this property is not important for the volatility, because training costs that are not sunk play a similar role." He shows that when these costs increase from 0% to 40% of average labor productivity, the volatility of the vacancies-unemployment ratio (measured by its elasticity) increases almost twofold, and it matches the observed volatility in the U.S. labor market.

In this paper, we evaluate the amplification mechanism of non-sunk fixed matching costs, and examine whether the cyclical volatility predicted by the model is substantially augmented. We show that when these costs are not sunk and, therefore, can be partially passed on to workers through lower wages, the volatility of the vacancy-unemployment ratio is approximately an order of magnitude less responsive to variations in these costs. Thus, from a quantitative standpoint, the contribution of matching costs in explaining labor-market volatility depends not only on the level, but also on what proportion of these costs is sunk. We also show that the model with fixed costs is equivalent to the standard model with lower labor productivity and nonconstant flow hiring costs. When we calibrate the model considering a share of sunk costs of 28% consistent with the empirical estimate of a small or a nearly neutral effect of training costs on the starting wage, the model is able to reproduce 96% of the observed volatility in the U.S. labor-market tightness. We observe, however, that this share of sunk costs introduces an unrealistic sensitivity to unemployment benefits (see Costain and Reiter 2008, for an explanation of this issue).

The paper is organized as follows. In Section II we incorporate non-sunk fixed costs in the standard MP model. Section III presents the calibration and the simulated elasticities. In Section IV, we present evidence related to the effect of training on the starting wage and check whether empirically reasonable training costs are able to match the volatility of unemployment. Finally, we present our conclusions in Section V.

II. THE MODEL

Given that our model is essentially the same as Pissarides' (2009), its presentation is reduced to a minimum. In this economy, there is a continuum of risk-neutral, infinitely lived workers and firms which discounts future payoffs at a common rate r; capital markets are perfect; and time is continuous. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

The Unemployment Volatility Puzzle: The Role of Matching Costs Revisited
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.