A Financial Transactions Tax: Inefficient or Needed Systemic Reform?

By Buckle, Ross P.; North, Gill | Georgetown Journal of International Law, Spring 2012 | Go to article overview

A Financial Transactions Tax: Inefficient or Needed Systemic Reform?


Buckle, Ross P., North, Gill, Georgetown Journal of International Law


TABLE OF CONTENTS

   I. INTRODUCTION
  II. FINANCIAL MARKET TRADING--THE FACTS
 III. PROPONENTS OF A FINANCIAL TRANSACTION TAX (FTT)
  IV. EUROPEAN COMMISSION REPORT
   V. IMF REPORTS
      A. A Fair and Substantial Contribution by the Financial Sector:
         IMF Staff Final Report for the G-20
      B. IMF Working Paper: Taxing Financial Transactions: Issues
         and Evidence
         1. Asset Valuation and Cost of Capital
         2. Turnover
         3. Liquidity
         4. Price Discovery
         5. Volatility
             i. Short-Term Volatility
            ii. Longer-Term Volatility
         6. Waste
         7. Matheson Conclusions
         8. Our Response to the Report Findings
  VI. THE ADMINISTRATIVE FEASIBILITY OF AN FTT
         1. Territorial Scope
         2. Taxable Event
         3. Tax Base
         4. Taxable Person
         5. Assessment & Collection of the Tax
 VII. RECENT FTT DEVELOPMENTS
VIII. CONCLUSION

I. INTRODUCTION

The global financial crisis (GFC) sparked vigorous debate on the role of financial institutions and capital markets, and the extent to which financial institutions and other capital market participants should contribute to the broader economy. Much of this debate has centred on the appropriate mechanisms to enable governments to recoup taxpayer monies used to bail out failing institutions and appropriate tax regimes going forward. Proposals considered at an international level have included financial institution levies (such as a financial stability contribution), a financial activities tax (FAT) and a financial transaction tax (FTT) (sometimes referred to as a securities transaction tax). France, Germany, the United Kingdom (UK), and other countries have already imposed levies on their financial industries to recoup bailout funds provided in the GFC, boost government revenues, and build a fund to help meet the cost of future crises. (1) This Article focuses on an FTT as a needed addition, or alternative to, bank levies. (2)

Critics of an FTT argue that a tax would have distorting effects on the function of the market and harm its efficiency due to reduced liquidity, higher volatility, and increased capital costs. (3) Those who support an FTT argue that by reducing trading volumes an FTT would enhance the ability of markets to allocate resources efficiently and allow important financial and human capital to be redeployed into more socially productive areas. Experts generally agree that collection of the tax through clearinghouses would be straightforward and cheap, and that tax avoidance can be minimized by applying the tax to a broad range of transactions across all jurisdictions. (4)

Staff of the European Commission (EC) and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) considered an FTT in 2010. Both of these reports rejected the tax in favor of other revenue raising schemes. The EC report indicated that "[e]ssentially, the debate on financial transaction taxes boils down to the question of the influence of transaction costs on trade volume and price volatility, and whether they can serve as a corrective device to reduce the number of allegedly harmful short-term traders." (5) Although the IMF report was more comprehensive in scope, it also focused primarily on short-term trading, liquidity, price discovery, volatility, and cost of capital effects.

This Article outlines and discusses the EC and IMF staff reports. We argue that the frameworks used to assess the efficiency, economic, and other effects of an FTT are unduly narrow. The primary argument in the reports is that increased trading leads to enhanced liquidity and lower transaction costs, which leads to lower costs of capital and improved economic outcomes (the trading cost of capital model). This argument is repeated like a mantra. However, the empirical research referenced in the reports is generally limited to microstructure studies, with the crucial links from the short-term price effects to long-term economic and community outcomes assumed rather than established. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

A Financial Transactions Tax: Inefficient or Needed Systemic Reform?
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.