Brave New Corporate World: An Assessment of Industrial Policy

By McIntyre, Richard; Hillard, Michael | Monthly Review, October 1984 | Go to article overview

Brave New Corporate World: An Assessment of Industrial Policy


McIntyre, Richard, Hillard, Michael, Monthly Review


BRAVE NEW CORPORATE WORLD: AN ASSESSMENT OF INDUSTRIAL POLICY

Public concern with the dangers of corporate power reached a feverish pitch in the early 1970s. Bills designed to control perceived abuses were passed by Congress, establishing the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) and the Occupational Safety and Health Agency (OSHA) and curbing the widespread practice of overseas bribery. This antimonopoly fervor peaked with the attempt to nationalize the oil industry, and with Congressional consideration of the Hart Deconcentration Act. Though these efforts failed, they placed the monopoly problem at the center of the liberal agenda.

Ten years later, worrying about monopoly seems quaint. The political ascendance of corporate reaction, combined with corporate "hired guns' from the University of Chicago and the American Enterprise Institute, have all but extinguished the antitrust movement. Nevertheless the basic tenet of twentieth-century liberalism--that capitalism can be reformed by wise state intervention--survives in the current school of industrial policy advocates. These neoliberals, an eclectic mix of lawyers, political scientists, labor and international trade economists, and a handful of politically active bankers and industrial capitalists, are providing the ideological bridge between academics and politicians for a new round of state intervention, much as an earlier group of intellectuals legitimized the macroeconomic finetuning advocated by American Keynesianism in the 1960s.

Conceding the debate on monopoly power to the right, industrial policy advocates tend to focus on the international economy. They emphasize the need to reorganize corporate management in the United States, with a view to enabling U.S.-based corporations to accommodate rationally to the changing structure of international trade. They argue that macroeconomic demand management is insufficient unless accompanied by mechanisms for dealing with change in industries, firms, and regions. The disturbing employment, profit, and growth statistics of the past fifteen years are seen as the consequence of corporate management's emphasis on short-run profits rather than long-run growth. For a variety of cultural and historical reasons, U.S. capitalism is said to be stuck with tax experts and "go-go' finance wizards at the economy's helm. Only prudent state intervention into the detailed functioning of the economy will prevent collapse under the weight of Japanese and third world imports.

Industrial policy appeals to many on the left as a sophisticated, activist response to reaction and economic crisis. At the end of the 1970s economists such as MIT's Lester Thurow and businessmen such as investment banker Felix Rohatyn began calling for state-led economic restructuring. While the views of these earlier advocates were criticized as being antidemocratic, more recent proponents of industrial policy--in particular Ira Magaziner and Robert Reich--have adopted a more democratic orientation.

After Reagan's anti-"big government' election swept many major Democratic politicans out of office and reduced the power of those who remained, the Democrats became a party "in search of ideas.' One of those ideas has been industrial policy. Robert Reich, Lester Thurow, and others were admitted to the inner circles of the Hart and Mondale campaigns. Indeed, the New York Times reported that, after reading Reich's The Next American Frontier, Mondale proclaimed: "This should do it for the Democrats in 1984.'

If the Democrats should succeed in deposing Reagan this year, a change in economic policy as sweeping as supply-side economics or the "New Economics' of the Kennedy-Johnson years may follow. Should the left applaud this? Should it "jump on the bandwagon'? Are there important criticisms to be mounted against this new version of liberalism?

Thurow's popular 1980 book, The Zero Sum Society, was the first coherent statement of the industrial-policy position. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Brave New Corporate World: An Assessment of Industrial Policy
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.