Is Inflation Dead?

By Brinner, Roger E. | New England Economic Review, January-February 1999 | Go to article overview

Is Inflation Dead?


Brinner, Roger E., New England Economic Review


In the past few years the United States has enjoyed the unique economic duet of very low unemployment and declining price inflation. For decades, we have come to associate tight labor markets with accelerating wages and prices. But in 1997, the unemployment rate sank below 5 percent and neither wage nor price inflation became a problem. Have our inflation processes fundamentally changed for the better? Are we in a new era of permanently better economic performance due to new behavior by our citizens? Or are we simply enjoying good luck in the form of positive supply shocks?

The overwhelming majority of research economists had previously estimated that an unemployment rate of about 6 percent was the lowest level that could be sustained. Below the vicinity of 6 percent, employers would compete aggressively for scarce labor by offering wage increases exceeding prevailing norms. The lower the unemployment rate, the greater the percentage wage gain would likely be. As wage increases pushed above existing price inflation and productivity gains, producers would raise prices to cover higher costs. The ensuing wage-price inflation spiral would not be broken until unemployment once more moved above 6 percent, a development typically caused by rising interest rates, as financial markets and the Federal Reserve reacted to the growing inflation problem.

The experience of the late 1980s seemed to confirm the modern validity of this decades-old perspective. The national unemployment rate fell from 6.2 percent in 1987 to 5.5 percent in 1988 and 5.3 percent in 1989; in response, wage increases jumped from 3.1 percent to 3.7 percent and then 4.2 percent. Wholesale price inflation rose from 1.9 percent in 1987 to 2.4 percent in 1988 and then to 3.9 percent in 1989; consumer price inflation jumped from 3.7 percent to 4.1 percent and on to 4.8 percent. Rising prices for imported goods, including oil, contributed significantly to the nation's inflation problems, but most of the blame was placed on excessive tension in domestic labor markets. In other words, lessons learned in the high-inflation 1970s had apparently been reinforced.

At first glance, the experience of recent years seems different. Price inflation remained in check from 1996 through 1998 even though unemployment rates fell further and further below 6 percent. It appeared natural to suspect that the balance point for U.S. labor markets should be recalibrated. Perhaps workers' insecurity was so intensified by the heavily publicized layoffs of the early 1990s that a lower unemployment rate was required before existing employees would demand norm-breaking pay increases.

Unfortunately, a more careful reading of the full inflation story reveals a different conclusion. Nominal wage inflation has been subdued by exceptionally modest price inflation. As can be seen in Figure 1, real, or price-adjusted, wage inflation has been increasing in response to low unemployment, just as in past decades. Price inflation has been held down by a set of "supply shocks," including a strong dollar, falling energy prices, and a cost-reducing regime shift in the health care industry. Moreover, most of these supply shocks are not novel ingredients of the inflation process in the United States. They have been studied and successfully used to understand price behavior for decades.

Inflation is not dead. However, recent supply shocks have shifted wage and price inflation to a lower zone. According to a revalidated, standard model of U.S. inflation, inflation can stay this low only if the unemployment rate rises to between 5.5 and 6 percent over the next year. Otherwise, as supply shocks shift to neutral or worse, tight labor markets will create a traditional inflation problem.

I. The Evolution of the Standard Model of Inflation

The original "Phillips Curve" (of the 1960s) presented a simple, inverse association between wage inflation (w) and the unemployment rate (u). …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Is Inflation Dead?
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.