Money Demand and Quantity Constraints: Evidence from the Soviet Interview Project

By Asgary, Nader; Gregory, Paul et al. | Economic Inquiry, April 1997 | Go to article overview

Money Demand and Quantity Constraints: Evidence from the Soviet Interview Project


Asgary, Nader, Gregory, Paul, Mokhtari, Manouchehr, Economic Inquiry


I. INTRODUCTION

There are more than 500 studies of money demand that use time-series or pooled data but less than twenty studies that use cross-section data. Time-series studies use a limited number of aggregate variables, such as income and wealth. Cross-section studies supplement income and wealth with socioeconomic and demographic variables to provide insights that cannot be detected in aggregate data. Most studies of money demand are for capitalist countries. Only a few studies exist for socialist countries.

There are no cross-section studies of the demand for money for socialist countries due to lack of data. Population censuses of the former Soviet Union did not provide information on household money and wealth (Pickersgill [1970] and Millar [1987]). However, the Soviet Interview Project (SIP) survey conducted in 1983 provides a large cross-section data set of former Soviet citizens. SIP is a retrospective survey of 2793 former Soviet citizens who left the Soviet Union for the United States during the late 1970s and early 1980s.

The SIP survey asked respondents about their last normal period of life in the Soviet Union. For most respondents this was in the late 1970s, a period of normal functioning of the administrative-command system. SIP provides a rich database of conventional variables, and includes information on rationing (EIAR) variables and other Soviet-specific variables. EIAR variables measure shortages, participation in the underground economy, and access to privileges. We examine the effects of EIAR factors on the demand for money in addition to conventional variables to obtain a picture of money demand near the end of the administrative-command era.

This paper makes two contributions. It is the first to examine the demand for money in a centrally planned economy using cross-section data which tests variables other than income and interest rates. Second, this study empirically investigates the effects of income on the marginal utility of income under rationing by studying how quantity-constrained respondents may use trade in convertible foreign currencies or barter when income increases, thereby lessening money's role as the medium of exchange.

The ongoing transformation of the former Soviet Union to a market economy and political pluralism is not an easy process. For policymakers, the findings of this study of the behavior of households may be useful in setting monetary policies (see also Collier and Mokhtari [1989], Ofer and Vinokur [1992], Mokhtari and Gregory [1993], and Mokhtari and Asgary [1993]). Policymakers must know the responses of households to changes in quantity constraints, underground economic activity, and privileges, and to other factors during the transition period and beyond. Moreover, our findings may be useful for researchers who investigate the behavioral differences in the money demand of households in two different economic systems.

II. PAST RESEARCH

In the administrative-command economy, money is held for transaction and precautionary purposes. Private capital markets are absent; investment decisions are made by the government. Money serves as a medium of exchange, and income should be the prime determinant of the demand for money. Under these conditions, money should be a necessity, and the income elasticity of demand for money should be positive and less than or equal to one.

Other than income, we would expect the demand for money in the Soviet Union to have different determinants than in capitalist countries. First, capital markets are absent; the interest rate is not the opportunity cost of money. Second, consumer good shortages (quantity constraints) should affect the transaction and the precautionary demand for money.(1) Households may substitute money for goods to be able to purchase goods in the future at state prices, purchase goods from the underground economy at higher prices, or reduce their labor supply (Barro and Grossman [1971; 1974; 1976]). …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA 8, MLA 7, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Note: primary sources have slightly different requirements for citation. Please see these guidelines for more information.

Cited article

Money Demand and Quantity Constraints: Evidence from the Soviet Interview Project
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen
Items saved from this article
  • Highlights & Notes
  • Citations
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA 8, MLA 7, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Search by... Author
    Show... All Results Primary Sources Peer-reviewed

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.