Value and Price: A Critique of Neo-Ricardian Claims

By Freeman, Alan | Capital & Class, October 2018 | Go to article overview

Value and Price: A Critique of Neo-Ricardian Claims


Freeman, Alan, Capital & Class


Introduction

Michel Husson originally published this landmark article in French (Perez, 1980) under the name Manuel Perez, 35 years ago. This translation provides an Anglophone audience with a historic contribution to our understanding of Marx's theory of value. It offers a new generation of Marx scholars a resource which academic Marxism has rejected, except for a minority tradition in which this article played a foundational role: the opportunity to understand, and grapple with, Marx's own economics.

My aim in this introduction is to explain, to such new readers, the key role which Husson's article played. It appeared 9years after Paul Samuelson (1971) pronounced Marx's value theory a failure, and 3 years after English Marxist Ian Steedman (1977) formally endorsed this verdict. Husson set out one of the first and in many ways the most comprehensive concise rebuttal of these claims. (1)

Several authors, at the time working independently, came to similar conclusions and in 1995 joined together to formalize them. Andrew Kliman proposed the term Temporal Single System interpretation (TSSI) of Marx to describe this school of thought, using the term 'Simultaneous Dual-System' interpretation (SDSI) to describe the interpretation employed by Samuelson, Steedman and most academic Marxists.

Husson's work was known to most early TSSI scholars, in particular the authors of Marx, Ricardo, Sraffa (Mandel and Freeman 1984) and those who subsequently wrote Marx and Non-Equilibrium Economics (Freeman and Carchedi 1996), the first definitive collaborative statement of TSSI. We regularly exchanged material in French, Italian and Spanish and were familiar with Husson's article. Yet unlike the above works, Husson's article remained unavailable in English and virtually unknown outside this circle.

Husson's pioneering critique engages the standpoint then known as 'Neoricardian'. This view, which still dominates academic Marxism (Freeman, 2010), had led most of its supporters by 1980 to conclude that Marx's economic arguments do not stand up to critical examination. Their judgement however stemmed from a particular reading, or interpretation, of Marx--the SDSI.

The distinction between a theory and an interpretation is critical, yet poorly understood. The confusion begins with the work of Tugan Baranowsky (1905) proposing a stationary equilibrium method for calculating values and prices of production upon which Bortkiewicz ([1906-1907] 1952, [1907] 1949) offered what he termed a 'correction' of Marx. Marx's mistake, says Von Bortkiewicz, is to suppose that value and price are formed in a 'succession' of periods. Famously, 'output' prices and values at the end of each period constitute the 'input' prices of the next period. This corresponds to the normal relations of market exchange, since sellers then receive the same money that the buyers pay.

Bortkiewicz, however, argued that the 'output' price of every commodity, that is the price it possesses when production is over, should be set equal to its price at the beginning of the same period, that is, before being produced. If value is treated in the same way, this yields two sets of simultaneous equations from which values, prices and the rate of profit are 'mutually' instead of 'successively' determined:

Alfred Marshall said once of Ricardo: 'He does not state clearly, and in some cases he perhaps did not fully and clearly perceive how, in the problem of normal value, the various elements govern one another mutually, not successively, in a long chain of causation'. This description applies even more to Marx ... [who] held firmly to the view that the elements concerned must be regarded as a kind of causal chain, in which each link is determined, in its composition and its magnitude, only by the preceding links ... Modern economics is beginning to free itself gradually from the successivist prejudice, the chief merit being due to the mathematical school led by Leon Walras. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA 8, MLA 7, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Note: primary sources have slightly different requirements for citation. Please see these guidelines for more information.

Cited article

Value and Price: A Critique of Neo-Ricardian Claims
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen
Items saved from this article
  • Highlights & Notes
  • Citations
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA 8, MLA 7, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Search by... Author
    Show... All Results Primary Sources Peer-reviewed

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.