What Is the Essence of Institutional Economics?

By Hodgson, Geoffrey M. | Journal of Economic Issues, June 2000 | Go to article overview

What Is the Essence of Institutional Economics?


Hodgson, Geoffrey M., Journal of Economic Issues


The term "institutional economics" was announced by Walton Hamilton at a meeting of the American Economic Association in 1918 [Hamilton 1919]. Institutionalism dominated American economics, at least until the 1940s. Listing a number of perceived attributes of this school, Walton Hamilton [1919, 309-11] claimed that institutional economics alone could unify economic science by showing how parts of the economic system related to the whole. Institutional economics was not defined in terms of any normative stance. Hamilton [1919, 313] declared: "It is not the place of economics to pass judgments upon practical proposals." However, its appeal as a theory was that allegedly it could be used as a basis for policy. According to Hamilton [1919, 314-18], institutional economists recognized that:

The proper subject-matter of economic theory is institutions.... Economic theory is concerned with matters of process.... Economic theory must be based upon an acceptable theory of human behavior...

This was expanded by the following observations:

neo-classical economics ... neglected the influence exercised over conduct by the scheme of institutions ... Where it fails, institutionalism must strive for success ... it must discern in the variety of institutional situations impinging upon individuals the chief source of differences in the content of their behavior [1919, 318].

Hamilton"s description of institutionalism requires refinement, but in its essentials it has endured the test of time. It can be rephrased and expanded in terms of the following five propositions:

1. Although institutional economists are keen to give their theories practical relevance, institutionalism itself is not defined in terms of any policy proposals.

2. Institutionalism makes extensive use of ideas and data from other disciplines such as psychology, sociology and anthropology in order to develop a richer analysis of institutions and of human behavior.

3. Institutions are the key elements of any economy, and thus a major task for economists is to study institutions and the processes of institutional conservation, innovation and change.

4. The economy is an open and evolving system, situated in a natural environment, effected by technological changes, and embedded in a broader set of social, cultural, political, and power relationships.

5. The notion of individual agents as utility-maximising is regarded as inadequate or erroneous. Institutionalism does not take the individual as given. Individuals are affected by their institutional and cultural situations. Hence individuals do not simply (intentionally or unintentionally) create institutions. Through "reconstitutive downward causation" [Hodgson 2000] institutions affect individuals in fundamental ways.

Most of these points are direct elaborations of ideas from Hamilton's [1919] text. However, regarding point (4), Hamilton did not mention the words "open system." The phrase did not become widely used until after 1945. Institutional economists such as K. William Kapp [1968, 8] and Shigeto Tsuru [1993, 73] made the idea of the economy as an open system one of the defining characteristics of institutionalism. Furthermore, Hamilton did not use the words "evolving" or "evolutionary," although institutionalists have become fond of these terms.

Point (1) may prove controversial, so it will be discussed in more detail below. It is perhaps the only point that any institutionalist may wish to remove from the list. Certainly, some institutionalists will wish to add to or elaborate on the above five points. The contention here is that they contain the "hard core" of the institutionalist tradition.

I further assert that the single most important defining characteristic of the old institutionalism is proposition (5). Among other schools, the new is distinguished from the old institutional economics principally in these terms. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

What Is the Essence of Institutional Economics?
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.