Property Rights Solutions for the Global Commons: Bottom-Up or Top-Down?

By Anderson, Terry L.; Grewell, J. Bishop | Duke Environmental Law & Policy Forum, Fall 1999 | Go to article overview

Property Rights Solutions for the Global Commons: Bottom-Up or Top-Down?


Anderson, Terry L., Grewell, J. Bishop, Duke Environmental Law & Policy Forum


I. INTRODUCTION

Environmental concerns often ignore geo-political borders. Problems that previously were dealt with by one nation and its government now involve scores of nations and their governments. At one time, policymakers focused predominantly on local matters, where pollutants might simply cross the boundary of two neighbors' backyards, or interstate problems, such as air and water pollution that could be handled within a nation or two. Now, however, policymakers are faced with international problems, such as the extinction of species, and global problems, such as ozone depletion and global warming.

Local environmental concerns are best understood and resolved in a framework initially developed by Nobel laureate Ronald H. Coase, wherein these concerns are viewed as a competition over conflicting uses for scarce resources.(1) In this context, air pollution by a factory is simply a use of air that conflicts with others' enjoyment of that resource. So, the question then becomes: which user has a right to the air?(2) Conflicting uses, such as in the air pollution example, can be resolved through bargaining if well-defined property rights specify who has the right to use the resources and therein derive value from them.(3)

The main question this article addresses is whether the Coasean property rights solution to environmental problems can be used as effectively on the international level as it has been used on the local level. Specifically, the authors pose the following two questions: (1) can effective property rights be created under international law, and (2) can and should such property rights be created top-down instead of bottom-up? In this article, "top-down" means government-mandated property rights, and "bottom-up" means customary, common law property rights that are formed over time when conflicts over resource use arise.

In addressing these questions, this article first contrasts the Coasean view of conflicting resource use with the Pigouvian view of externalities. It then considers the importance of time- and place-specific information in the evolution of property rights to determine how they are established. Then, the article contrasts bottom-up property rights with the prospect of developing effective top-down property rights and provides examples of both. Acknowledging that transaction costs may thwart privatization of the global commons (e.g., the global atmosphere), it then addresses the limits of top-down solutions and offers policy suggestions that build on property rights and the rule of law.

II. TWO VIEWS OF THE COMMONS: PIGOU VS. COASE

Following A. C. Pigou,(4) the dominant policy approach for solving environmental problems has been to use government's power to tax and regulate.(5) Government intervention is seen as justified when externalities exist. The term "externality" refers to an economic concept asserting that inefficiencies result when costs incurred and benefits received by individuals involved in an economic transaction or activity do not incorporate all the costs and benefits to society.(6) Therefore, a transaction that seems efficient to the individual parties to a transaction may really be inefficient from the viewpoint of society because of the existence of externalities.(7) Negative externalities are present when a portion of the costs of an economic transaction are imposed on others outside of that transaction without their consent. According to this reasoning, negative externalities result in overproduction or over-use of resources, because resource users do not bear the full costs associated with their activities.(8) This problem can turn into a "tragedy of the commons" when every user of a commons receives the full marginal benefit from their use, but bears only a portion of the marginal cost.(9)

Coase, however, offered a different approach to the problem of social cost.(10) Coase did not think in terms of externalities, but rather considered pollution and clean air (or water, forests, wildlife habitat) as conflicting or alternative resource uses for which there is competition. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Property Rights Solutions for the Global Commons: Bottom-Up or Top-Down?
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.