Thinking about a "New Economy

By Taylor, Timothy | The Public Interest, Spring 2001 | Go to article overview

Thinking about a "New Economy


Taylor, Timothy, The Public Interest


THE Industrial Revolution that began about 200 years ago lives in the collective memory as a cavalcade of inventors and machines: James Watt and the steam engine, Eli Whitney and the cotton gin, Cyrus McCormick and the reaper, Charles Goodyear and vulcanized rubber, and many more. But the Industrial Revolution brought a remarkable change in the human condition that went beyond any particular invention. It instilled a belief that the standard of living did not have to be forever stagnant.

Looking back from today's privileged vantage point, after two centuries of economic growth, it may be impossible to feel in our bones what it meant to live in a world without economic progress. Consider, for example, the note of genuine wonder in the voice of Karl Marx, writing of the new realities in the Communist Manifesto in 1848:

The bourgeoisie during its rule of scarce one hundred years has created more massive and more colossal productive forces than have all preceding generations together. Subjection of nature's forces to man, machinery, application of chemistry to industry and agriculture, steam-navigation, railways, electric telegraphs, clearing of whole continents for cultivation, canalization of rivers, whole populations conjured out of the ground-what earlier century had even a presentiment that such productive forces slumbered in the lap of social labour?

Modern economists, with their highly developed talent for reducing the drama of human production and consumption to dry statistics, describe the Industrial Revolution more simply: It was the era when economic growth in countries like the United States rose from essentially nothing to 2 percent per year. This 2 percent growth rate should not be understood as a physical constant like the boiling point of water but rather as a rough guideline to the average experience of the most highly developed economies over the last two centuries.

A 2 percent growth rate may sound small to those who have not doodled with a calculator and the magic of compound growth rates. But, at a humble 2 percent per capita annual rate of growth, the average standard of living doubles in 36 years; quadruples in 72 years; and will rise roughly 50-fold over two centuries. The change from almost no increase in the average standard of living over several millennia, until 1800, to a 50-fold increase in the next two centuries is what the Industrial Revolution has meant to those who live in developed countries.

In recent years, there has been considerable discussion of whether the development and application of information and communications technology have changed the U.S. economy in a fundamental way, promising a golden future of rapid growth, low unemployment and inflation, perpetual economic expansion, and a booming stock market. The change is sometimes called the "Information Revolution"; more commonly, it is called the "New Economy." While there is sound evidence that the U.S. economy has experienced a revival in productivity growth since the mid 1990s, the argument that it has undergone either a fundamental shift in its patterns or a change on the scale of the Industrial Revolution appears overblown.

What's in a name?

There are three distinct senses in which the development and dispersion of information and communications technology could qualify as a "revolution." One would be that just as the Industrial Revolution increased the annual per capita rate of growth by two percentage points a year, from zero to 2 percent, the Information Revolution should raise the per capita growth rate by an additional two percentage points, from 2 percent to 4 percent. Such a change would represent a phenomenal shift in the human condition. Again doodling with a calculator, an annual per capita growth rate of 4 percent per year, sustained over two centuries, would mean a staggering 2,500-fold increase in the standard of living.

A less exacting standard for the Information Revolution would be that a new set of inventions will carry the economy forward at its 2 percent annual growth rate. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Thinking about a "New Economy
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.