Democracy or Bust?

By Chan, Yu Ping | Harvard International Review, Fall 2001 | Go to article overview

Democracy or Bust?


Chan, Yu Ping, Harvard International Review


The Development Dilemma

For Amartya Sen, winner of the 1998 Nobel Prize for economics, it was clear: "The most important thing that has happened in the 20th century is democracy." Yet today, for many developing countries in Africa, Eastern Europe, Latin America, and Asia, the value of democracy is not quite this self-evident. While Western nations preach "democratization" as the key to economic progress, the developing nations themselves must determine the best form of governance and the best economic policy that will drive their countries forward.

In opposition to its knee-jerk appeal, some have argued that "democracy"-the presence of freely elected institutions and the ability to participate in them--is unnecessary and is, in fact, an obstacle to the progress of developing countries. There are theoretical arguments, empirical evidence, and events from recent history that may appear to support this thesis; yet, upon closer examination, the bulk of the argument proves untenable. Indeed, democracy is a factor that promotes economic growth. Though it cannot guarantee increases in a nation's GDP or per capita income, the practice of democracy is critical for long-term sustainable growth.

Centralized Power

Resistance to democracy arises from the belief that a strong central government is more conducive to development than democratic institutions. In particular, the influence of populism on policy formation is seen as the major drawback of democratic government. Since a democracy is dependent on the will of the people, some argue that such governments are less likely to make necessary but politically unpopular economic decisions; on the other hand, an authoritarian government could theoretically take necessary economic measures with an eye toward the long-term good without fear of reprisal at the ballot box.

For instance, several historians have attributed Russia's economic disarray after the breakup of the Soviet Union to Russian President Boris Yeltsin's untimely introduction of democracy. In 1992, implementation of Russian Finance Minister Yegor Gaidar's "shock therapy"--abolishing price controls on all goods--was delayed because it was highly unpopular. This delay was a move that economists have widely criticized, and it undermined later economic reform.

Conversely, officials may formulate popular but economically unviable policies, catering to the short-term desires of the masses rather than following a long-term economic blueprint. India, Asia's largest democracy, has often excused its economic failures as the "price of democracy"--frequent elections and proportional representation meant weak coalition governments that followed public opinion slavishly and isolated India from the world economy.

However, political decisions are neither made in a vacuum nor based completely on public opinion. Although democracy may make government sensitive to the people's desires, this may be seen as insurance against the opposite: an oppressive government insensitive to the people's needs. An open political system helps root out pervasive corruption, which hurts development and discredits public authority. With democracy, a government has to account for its policies before an ever-demanding public, thus ensuring greater transparency and reining in corruption. Even as some argue that corruption is not intrinsic to undemocratic government and that an autocrat might be willing to forgo bounty in the near term to enhance long-term growth prospects and future revenues, evidence to the contrary abounds. Zaire's Mobutu Sese Seko, the Philippines' Ferdinand Marcos, and Kenya's Daniel arap Moi are just a few prominent examples of the corrupt dictators produced by a lack of transparency within the system. Without accountabili ty to the people, there is no way of ensuring that undemocratic governments deliver the goods.

Getting Results

Yet critics of democracy say that in the area of economic-policy implementation, undemocratic governments may be superior because, unlike democracies, they are not beset by constantly changing governments, bureaucracies, and interest groups. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Democracy or Bust?
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.