From Socialism to the Market Economy: Postwar West Germany versus Post-1989 East Bloc

By Pejovich, Svetozar | Independent Review, Summer 2001 | Go to article overview

From Socialism to the Market Economy: Postwar West Germany versus Post-1989 East Bloc


Pejovich, Svetozar, Independent Review


Socialist writers all presume that socialist institutions can bring about a "just" society. This premise has provided both the philosophical foundation and the political justification for the practitioners of socialism to replace individual liberties and the rule of law with the rule of men (hereafter, "the arbitrary state") and a display of concern for "the people." The latter term, a favorite of all socialist leaders, is a mere facade behind which the ruling elite hide their own private ends.

The twentieth century witnessed the trial and failure of two major applications of socialist doctrine: national socialism and Marxism-Leninism. Like competing families in the underworld, national socialism and Marxism-Leninism went to war (hot and cold) with each other as well as with the rest of the world. Both failed to deliver on their promises. Defeat in World War II destroyed Hitler's socialism, whereas Marxism-Leninism decayed from within and ultimately collapsed as a rotten hulk.

National socialists and communists shared many basic political and economic premises of socialist doctrine. Both operated a command economy and made the individual a mere instrument for the achievement of the ends of their ruling elites. Both despised the private-property, free-market economy and its corollary, the society of free and responsible individuals. They favored a large, active state, created comprehensive welfare programs, and paid no heed to the rule of law. National socialism and Marxism-Leninism were equally unrelenting in the pursuit of their primary targets: inferior races and the bourgeoisie, respectively.

They also had some fundamental differences. Communists were openly hostile to the private right of ownership, whereas national socialists settled for monitoring and controlling the behavior of ostensible private owners. National socialists regarded the struggle for racial purity within national boundaries as the major mechanism for the development of their brand of socialism. Communists, on the other hand, considered the class struggle waged by the proletariat across national boundaries as the vehicle for the development of the Marxist-Leninist type of socialism. In 1972, Nicolae Ceausescu, the communist leader of Romania, tried to bridge the gap between nationalism and internationalism, declaring: "The dialectical process of bringing together nations presupposes their strong affirmation.... Between national and international interests not only is there no contradiction, but, on the contrary, there is a full dialectical unity" (qtd. in Berlin 1992, 253-54).

Clearly, it was the failure of socialist experiments that gave rise to the institutional restructuring of the former socialist states after 1989. The objectives of that institutional restructuring, however, are less clear. The leaders of former socialist states talk about achieving liberty, social stability, and sustained economic growth, but those stated objectives have frequently misrepresented these leaders' real goals. Indisputably, the economic reforms mirror the leaders' preferences, their philosophical premises, the political and economic constraints on their decision-making powers, and the incentives under which they operate. Observed results also incorporate the effects of uncertainties, incomplete information, and divergence of interests between policymakers and those who implement policies.

Institutional changes in former socialist states have produced results that raise some important questions. For example, why was the transition of West Germany in the 1950s more successful than the institutional restructuring of the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe in the 1990s? Why do the results of institutional restructuring within the former Soviet bloc differ from one country to another? Why do we observe no tendency in former socialist states for more-efficient institutions to replace less-efficient ones?

In this article, I identify the rule of law, the carriers of institutional restructuring, and the prevailing informal rules of the community as three critical determinants of the outcome of institutional restructuring. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

From Socialism to the Market Economy: Postwar West Germany versus Post-1989 East Bloc
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.