Regulatory Lessons from the South Korean Currency Crisis: A Reply to Jai S. Mah. (Notes and Communications)

By Zalewski, David A. | Journal of Economic Issues, September 2002 | Go to article overview

Regulatory Lessons from the South Korean Currency Crisis: A Reply to Jai S. Mah. (Notes and Communications)


Zalewski, David A., Journal of Economic Issues


Professor Jai S. Mah criticizes my "Brothers, Can You Spare $58 Billion? Regulatory Lessons from the South Korean Currency Crisis" (henceforth, "Brothers") for failing to describe the underlying causes of the crisis and for neglecting to recognize the International Monetary Fund's contribution to South Korea's unexpected economic recovery. Although Mah correctly points out some minor faults in my paper, I argue below that the basic lessons described in "Brothers" were not only relevant at the time it was written but remain so today.

What Caused the Crisis, and Could It Have Been Prevented?

"Brothers" began by evaluating Thomas F. Cargill's (1998) claim that regulatory forbearance, moral hazard, and excessive risk taking were the primary causes of the South Korean crisis. According to Cargill, these problems resulted from the government's unwillingness to completely liberalize the financial sector. Although my paper acknowledged the solvency problems stressed by Cargill such as the increase in nonperforming loans and rising chaebol bankruptcy rates in early 1997, it also stated: "Equally troublesome, however, was the fact that the financial system had become increasingly fragile and susceptible to a liquidity crisis" (360, emphasis added). "Brothers" observed that this condition developed after the liberalization of short-term capital inflows in 1993 enabled bankers to respond to increasing global competition by financing long-term domestic loans with short-term, foreign currency-denominated liabilities. This exposed banks to shocks that could impair their ability to meet cash flow obligations, potentially leading to the type of debt/deflation spiral described by Hyman Minsky (1986). (1) Thus, "Brothers" concluded that South Korea suffered from both solvency and liquidity problems at the time of the crisis and that the latter resulted from the misguided decision to liberalize short-term capital flows while the banking sector was weak and before effective regulatory institutions were established.

Although Mah argues that the "root cause" of the crisis was an increase in nonperforming loans, his criticism of excessive short-term borrowing suggests that he also believes liquidity problems played a role. Therefore, Mah's claim that I "did not reveal the deep-rooted causes" of the crisis is inappropriate since we only disagree about the relative importance of these factors. The events that Mah considers to be responsible for the onset of the crisis--chaebol failures, the government's bailout of Kia, and the Hong Kong stock market crash--worried lenders and motivated many of them to withdraw their loans. Because any of a variety of shocks could have triggered the crisis, however, the type of initiating impulse is less important than the underlying susceptibility of the financial system.

Based on this interpretation, "Brothers" recommended that regulators should strive to prevent financial fragility, especially since global deregulation has forced bankers to assume greater risks to maintain profitability. This implies that financial liberalization should be delayed until regulators adopt some variation of Minsky's (1975) cash flow-based bank examination procedure that focuses on preventing financial crises by gauging the potential impact of macroeconomic developments on banking conditions. My paper also encouraged bankers to adopt risk management practices to supplement regular bank examinations by government auditors. Although Mah claims that I neglected to propose the development of an early warning system, I believe these reforms would have performed this function.

Was the IMF's Response Appropriate?

Responding to South Korea's request for assistance as it depleted its foreign exchange reserves in defense of the won, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) approved approximately US$58 billion in standby credit on December 4, 1997. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA 8, MLA 7, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Note: primary sources have slightly different requirements for citation. Please see these guidelines for more information.

Cited article

Regulatory Lessons from the South Korean Currency Crisis: A Reply to Jai S. Mah. (Notes and Communications)
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen
Items saved from this article
  • Highlights & Notes
  • Citations
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA 8, MLA 7, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Search by... Author
    Show... All Results Primary Sources Peer-reviewed

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.