Crisis Theory and the False Desire of Home Ownership

By Wendling, Amy E. | Philosophy Today, May 2011 | Go to article overview

Crisis Theory and the False Desire of Home Ownership


Wendling, Amy E., Philosophy Today


In the 1848 Manifesto of the Communist Party, Marx mentions

the commercial crises that by their periodical return put on trial, each time more threateningly, the existence of the entire bourgeois society. ... In these crises there breaks out an epidemic that, in all earlier epochs, would have seemed an absurdity - the epidemic of over-production __ And how does the bourgeoisie get over these crises? On the one hand by enforced destruction of a mass of productive forces; on the other, by the conquest of new markets, and by the more thorough exploitation of the old ones. That is to say, by paving the way for more extensive and more destructive crises, and by diminishing the means whereby crises are prevented.1

Though Marx will develop his crisis theory at length in other, later works, and particularly in Capital, the essential moments of his argument are already present here.2 These moments are: ( 1 ) empirical observation of a single commercial crisis; (2) overcoming singular or idiosyncratic aspects of this crisis in order to link it to a series of cyclical crises; (3) charting a causal path between features internal to capitalism and these recurrent crises, thereby refuting the objection that crisis results from accident, from features external to capitalism, or that it can be controlled while remaining within the capitalist mode of production; and, finally, (4) suggesting that commercial crises will worsen as the mode of production known as capitalism develops.

Following this argument, economists influenced by Marx's crisis theory meet the advent of a new, empirical commercial crisis with an utter lack of surprise and rapidly begin the theoretical work of linking it to other economic crises. Some even attempt to predict when a crisis will again occur.3

From Marx's perspective, crises are simply inevitable, given the causal and structural features of the capitalist mode of production. The questions are: when will they happen, what will be their worsening features, and how can capitalism be eliminated?

History has a way of asserting itself definitively, but only briefly. Our memories are not strong, particularly when the patterns to be charted exceed the imaginative threshold of a single human lifetime. In addition, the static modeling features of mainstream economics, combined with a positivist methodology inherently opposed to conceptual scrutiny, jointly militate against the kind of longitudinal and structural analysis that Marxist crisis theory mandates.4 Insofar as we react with naïve surprise in acknowledging any given economic crisis, we will only ever discover solutions to crisis that, in the words of Marx, "pave the way for more extensive and destructive crises."

However, to understand the inner logic of the mode of production known as capitalism, we will have to detour through the history of a discipline that has been lost, particularly in North America: political economy. The essay therefore proceeds in five sections:

I. A brief history of this lost discipline and Marx's place in it.

II. A discussion of periodic economic crises, such as the Great Depression of the 1 930s and the Great Stagflation of the 1 970s, along with a documentation of the resurgences in crisis theory that have accompanied these historical events.

III. An argument that recurrent economic crises have a common source in a feature that, according to Marx, is structurally endemic to capital: the fall in the rate of profit.

IV. A consideration of the 2008 economic crisis in light of these reflections; and, in conclusion:

V. A broader treatment of the notion of crisis outside of the confines of commerce.

I. Political Economy

Though the term "political economy" derives from a cluster of French thinkers associated with physiocracy, perhaps the most important figure in the early years of the discipline was Adam Smith. Smith wrote two very famous works: A Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759), a work of moral theory, and An Inquiry into the Nature and the Causes of the Wealth of Nations (1776), the classic foundational work of political economy. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Crisis Theory and the False Desire of Home Ownership
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.