Why Most Things Fail: Evolution, Extinction and Economics

By Walsh, Grace | Irish Journal of Management, July 1, 2011 | Go to article overview

Why Most Things Fail: Evolution, Extinction and Economics


Walsh, Grace, Irish Journal of Management


Why Most Things Fail: Evolution, Extinction and Economics by Paul Ormerod London: Faber and Faber Ltd, 2005

Given the pervasive nature of failure currently undermining economies, this book presents itself as a one-stop shop to dissecting the disposition of economic and societal collapse. In reality it is more a high concept book which offers little in the way of practical advice for managers of ailing firms in today's tumultuous climate. However, what the book successfully offers is a thought-provoking, fresh perspective on failure in markets, governments and societies. Why Most Things Fail is a fusion of ideas that draws from economics to biology, history to mathematics and psychology to physics. The author is keenly inspired by Hayek, the 1974 co-Nobel Laureate in Economics, whom he cites within the text as saying, 'An economist who is only an economist cannot be a good economist' (p. 226); it is clear from the beginning of the book that this is a mantra Ormerod strongly believes in. The text commences by introducing the reader to the Iron Law of Failure, which highlights the permeating nature of failure; according to Ormerod extinction eventually strikes, in fact, '99.99% of all biological species which have ever existed are now extinct' (p. ix). This statistic becomes increasingly daunting when the author presents a link between the extinction of biological species and the failure of companies. The juxtaposed relationship between biological species and economic organisations is the most intriguing argument presented in the book. The author puts forth his model, that the mathematical relationship which illustrates the link 'between the frequency and size of the extinction of companies ...is virtually identical to that which describes the extinction of biological species in the fossil record' (p. x). While this statement sounds rather outlandish it provides a great backdrop to illustrate the grave differences between the cold, logical agents that underpin most economic theories and the complex, evolving, instinctive firms that are indicative of real life and exemplified within the text. It is also noted that a fundamental difference between biological evolution and the evolution of the firm is that companies are run by individuals acting in a strategic manner with the intent of becoming increasingly fit for survival, whereas 'the process of evolution of biological species cannot be planned' (p. xi).

The next section of the book (Chapters 2, 3 and 4) examines issues such as inequality, social segregation and poor social mobility in the context of both the economy and broader society as failure is inherent yet highly undesirable in these areas. Some thought-provoking concepts are raised in this section, such as the 'diamond back', where the minority elite live in the confines of a diamond-shaped enclosure and pass on privileges to their children, while the less fortunate majority live in their own diamond and the two diamonds are connected by a narrow isthmus which a rare few will ever cross, and although education can be and is being used as an instrument to increase the level of social mobility across the classes the rate of social mobility has been consistently falling from the late 1960s up to the present day (p. 41). Social segregation is examined using Manchester's disparate social classes and territories as an example because they remain distinctly separate to such a degree that it is very similar in 2004 to what it was in 1844, despite generations of social reformers working towards social cohesion and integration (p. 60). According to the author, the failure of policy makers to overcome these societal injustices could be explained to a degree by Schelling's geographical segregation model. Schelling's model involves a massive chessboard-style layout with an equal number of two types of agents, which populate across the board in a random, scattered fashion. The game progresses by each agent being allowed to move individually and choosing to move if there is less than a specified percentage of its neighbours of the same type as itself. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Why Most Things Fail: Evolution, Extinction and Economics
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.