The Fortunes of Economics

By Robertson, David | Review - Institute of Public Affairs, March 2004 | Go to article overview

The Fortunes of Economics


Robertson, David, Review - Institute of Public Affairs


The Fortunes of Economics Economics and its Enemies: Two Centuries of Anti-Economics by William Oliver Coleman (Palgrave-Macmillan, London, 2002, hardback, 328 pages, A$198)

In this excellent work of scholarship, the Tasmanian academic William Coleman reviews the attacks on economics that have persisted since its foundation and which continue unabated today. In the opening chapter, the author draws the battlelines between the accusers and the defendants, and describes the field of action. This patient and methodical introduction leads into a careful and balanced description of two centuries of conflict over economics.

This absorbing study provides not only detailed information and a telling commentary, it is also entertaining. Coleman organizes the many sources of criticism and condemnation directed at economics and economists, starting with Smith, Hume and the Physiocrats, and following the trail until economics reached maturity with Marshall and the Marginalist School. He makes a genuine assessment of both sides of the argument, explaining the confusions caused by economic texts as well as the malicious self-indulgence of the enemies of economics. Yet he is never condescending and restricts his judgements to the final chapter. His patience must have been sorely tested by such restraint.

The lesson is that the enemies of economics are drawn principally from political interests of one sort or another. For the most part, these enemies defame rather than discredit any analysis or logical argument that weakens or undermines their rhetoric. Their goal is to destroy economics as an intellectual pursuit; to demolish its precepts rather than simply to criticize.

This is illustrated by the contradictory use of economics in the revolutions that ended the Age of Enlightenment. Economic reasoning based on self-interest and economic freedom brought by markets was first decried as anti-monarchist and disruptive of social order in the lead-up to the French Revolution. This was then condemned when the Republic was established because 'the citizens' saw self-interest as supporting hierarchy. When the monarchy was restored economics was again regarded as disruptive of law and order. Some would argue that this confusion about economics has remained with French politics until the present day!

Although Classical economists regarded themselves as apolitical, economics generated strong reactions in political circles. The Age of Revolution saw Napoleon establish aggressive nationalism, following the United States' more peaceful model. Nationalism elevated public policy and history/culture above abstract economic theory. The rise of the new Germany in 1870 coincided with the establishment of The German Historical School which introduced the inductive historical method into economics. Economics had to be part of national development. The protectionism advocated earlier by Hamilton and List was incorporated into industrial policy and mercantilism revived. This all-encompassing nationalism was to exact an enormous price from Europe in the next hundred years! The German Historical School is now part of history but, Coleman notes, its ghosts linger in so-called 'development economies'.

Politicians' concerns about economics and nationalism are nowhere better illustrated than in Coleman's chapter on economists in Totalitarian States. Stalin would not tolerate alternative opinions. First he bullied, then brutalised eminent Russian economists, before he eradicated them. This must have been a considered decision because he is reported to have had a large collection of economics books that he had annotated. This chapter is disturbing to read because memories of the Stalinist monster-state and Hitler's Third Reich are revived. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

The Fortunes of Economics
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.