The Use of Accounting Information in Governmental Regulation and Public Administration: The Impact of John R. Commons and Early Institutional Economists

By Covaleski, Mark A.; Dirsmith, Mark W. et al. | The Accounting Historians Journal, June 1995 | Go to article overview

The Use of Accounting Information in Governmental Regulation and Public Administration: The Impact of John R. Commons and Early Institutional Economists


Covaleski, Mark A., Dirsmith, Mark W., Samuel, Sajay, The Accounting Historians Journal


An earlier version of this paper was presented at The Academy of Accounting Historians' Accounting Biography Conference, University of Mississippi, December 3 and 4, 1994. We wish to thank Janice Mereba, Barbara Merino, John Russell, and the anonymous reviewers for their useful suggestions.

Received August 1994 Revised March 1995 Accepted August 1995

Commons' contribution has not been fully explored or recognized within the accounting literature.

INTRODUCTION

A myriad of such social innovations as workmen's compensation, social security, unemployment insurance, and utility and industrial regulation had their origins within the combined intellectual/political base of John R. Commons' institutional school of economics at the University of Wisconsin, and Governor Robert La Follette's Progressive party in the State of Wisconsin. Wisconsin's efforts, in turn, became the epicenter of socio-public administrative experimentation and served as a model for reform by other states and the federal government

Roosevelt, 1912, pp. v-ix; Kolko, 1963, pp. 212-216

. The stated purposes of this combined intellectual/political base were to modify the government's role in response to changing social as well as technical/industrial conditions, and simultaneously engender and benefit from the efficient administration of the American political economy.

Hays

1959, pp. 261-276

has suggested that the turn-of-the-century Progressive movement attracted institutional economists like John R. Commons who advocated the "rational" deployment of public resources, supported by a complex of such rationalizing techniques as accounting, to solve broad social problems. This movement served to legitimize a system of decision making based on calculated criteria thought to be objective, rational and above the give-and-take of political maneuvering. It made the political seem apolitical

Rose, 1977, pp. 68-71

; it took the debatable beyond the realm of open debate

Hopwood, 1984, pp. 170-176

; and it differentiated the political and immoral from the objective and merely factual

Zucker, 1977, pp. 733-738; Miller and O'Leary, 1990, pp. 492-498

. This movement sought to substitute and legitimize one system of decision-making -- the one inherent in the spirit of modern science, technology and business -- for another -- the one inherent in stylized but subjective exchanges among overtly political social actors. Decision making and control became a more calculative, procedurally-oriented process, involving measurement and prediction, that invoked business techniques for directing the course of events toward predictable and stable outcomes

Kolko, 1963, pp. 1-10

. This shift moved decision making away from the local government to the larger networks of human interaction, and it achieved more than legitimate a new form of decision making; it also transferred power to the central executive office

Wilson, 1956, pp. 98-117

. As Hays

1959, pp. 261-276

suggested, an examination of the Progressive movement illuminates not so much the content of public policy, but the nature of the resulting political structure and the types of interactions peculiar to it.

The primary purpose of our paper is to trace the intellectual underpinnings of John R. Commons' institutional economics in order to appreciate the impact of Commons' work on the use of accounting information in turn-of-the-century governmental regulation and public administration. (1) It is proposed that John Commons joined such other pragmatists of the era as John Dewey

1910, 1922

and Thorstein Veblen

1904, 1919

to critique the inequities created by the concentration of wealth during the late nineteenth century, as embodied in such monopolies as railroads and utilities. However, departing both from pragmatists who contended that the "pecuniary calculus of accounting" was dysfunctional to the interests of society

e. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

The Use of Accounting Information in Governmental Regulation and Public Administration: The Impact of John R. Commons and Early Institutional Economists
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.